People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXVI No. 40 October 13,2002 |
Politics
And The Disinvestment Controversy
C
P Chandrasekhar
PRIME
MINISTER Vajpayee has made one more effort at putting to rest the embarrassing
controversy within the NDA government and the Sangh Parivar over the
privatisation of oil majors HPCL and BPCL. In his address at the launch of the
Tenth Five Year Plan document, which provides for an 8 per cent rate of growth,
he made the case that economic reform would have to be persisted with if the
rate of growth has to be increased. And the principal plank of the current phase
of reform is, in his view and that of many others, the accelerated privatisation
of profitable public sector assets. In fact, in an almost orchestrated move,
representatives of domestic and foreign capital, of the IMF and the World Bank
and of international finance (like Standard and Poor) have been arguing that:
(1) the setback to the Shourie-style strategic “disinvestment” of the last
two years that the oil privatisation controversy implies, is a setback to the
process of economic reform; and (2) the slowing of economic reform is
responsible for the sluggishness in growth in recent months. After the size of
the fiscal deficit, the slow pace of public sector sell-off has emerged as
India’s second most important economic problem. Unemployment and poverty do
not seem to feature in this list at all.
INNER
POWER STRUGGLE
The
controversy over whether HPCL and BPCL should be put on the block as part of the
process of strategic sale, involving the hand over of management control to a
private buyer of as little as 26 per cent of equity in a PSU, has found the
disinvestment minister Arun Shourie arraigned on one side with support from the
prime minister, standing up to a motley combination consisting of petroleum
minsiter Ram Naik, defence minister George Fernandes and human resource
development minister Murali Manohar Joshi, who as a group seem to have the tacit
even if not wholehearted support of the deputy prime minsiter L.K. Advani.
Among
those opposed to proceeding further with privatisation based on a sale of key
oil sector PSUs, the concerns of petroleum minister Ram Naik, who is informed by
opinion within his own ministry and by the loss of turf that the sale of HPCL
and BPCL would involve, are the easiest to understand. The motivation of George
Fernandes, on the other hand, who has been the most vocal advocate for caution,
is still unclear. He had earlier argued that experience indicates that
privatisation is not yielding the promised benefits and political returns for
the NDA government. That it is in fact imposing unexpected costs, and could
generate strategic risks in some areas. On these grounds he had in fact called
for a mid-course review and a possible “course correction”. Now, it appears,
he has rescinded, as has been his wont on many an issue. He has reportedly
declared that he has not been against privatisation and had only called for a
review, which may (or may not) necessitate a correction. Not being known for
being particularly consistent in his formulations, this opportunistic dilution
of his position by Mr. Fernandes was in all probability expected. The problem is
that principal role it would serve is to help discredit the strong and already
well-articulated case against the disinvestment of profitable public sector
enterprises .
Finally,
Murali Manohar Joshi, who has joined the group of dissenters, appears to be
articulating the RSS-Swadeshi Jagran Manch line that all is not well with the
NDA’s economic policy, which is seen as excessively market and foreign capital
oriented. This is in keeping with the BJP’s earlier nationalist rhetoric that
the NDA has completely given up in practice This foray by Mr. Joshi into the
economic realm, while surprising given his past relative silence on such
matters, is possibly indicative of a new struggle for power within the
increasingly complex Sangh Parivar combination.
Given
all this it is clear that the “disinvestment controversy” is more a battle
for political space within the Sangh Parivar and the NDA rather than an
ideological effort at mid-course correction. This feature of the controversy has
two adverse consequences. First, the actual merits of the case against
disinvestment are being ignored, because the correctness of the policy is not
being assessed conceptually, but in terms of whether its implementation in
practice has belied expectations. Second, it allows those who claim to be
technocratic defenders of the efficient market mechanism to claim that a correct
marketist, pro-disinvestment position is being challenged by “vested
interests” and subverted by politics.
WHY
NO TO DISINVESTMENT
The
case against disinvestment of profit-making public sector enterprises like HPCL
and BPCL has been made often enough. These enterprises are capable of earning
returns that are well above the rate of interest on government bonds. In fact it
is because they are capable of earning such returns that private agents see them
as attractive purchases. For these private sector players, public sector bonds
are a risk-free source of return, making the yields on such bonds the floor to
the expected rate of return on investment. Unless purchases of public sector
equity are expected to more than cover this floor as well as provide for an
additional margin to cover the risk associated with investment in such equity,
disinvestment offers are unlikely to find any takers. In the circumstances, it
is unclear why the government itself should not retain this return and cover the
costs of whatever expenditure is going to be met with disinvestment proceeds by
issuing debt at an interest rate that is more than covered by the yield on
equity. Further, the fact that the yield on equity needs to be higher than the
interest rate on government bonds makes nonsense of the argument that
disinvestment proceeds should be used to retire public debt and reduce the
interest outgo on the government’s budget.
Despite
this very obvious and direct reason why disinvestment of profitable public
sector units should not occur, the government has been desperate to go in for
partial privatisation through the strategic sale route. The facts that this
route involves only partial sale of say 26 per cent of equity to a single buyer,
and that such sale is strategic or is accompanied by the handover of managerial
control to the buyer are both indicative of the massive concessions that the
government has to provide to make disinvestment a successful initiative.
Clearly, private buyers are not willing to risk too much of their own capital in
a single enterprise making it difficult for the government to find buyers for
outright purchase of its equity stake in full. In addition, private players are
obviously not keen to hold a minority stake in the equity of a unit that the
government manages. Faced with these two behavioural responses of the private
sector to its privatisation effort, the government in a desperate
bid to make its disinvestment programme a success, has had to offer the private
sector substantial control over profitable productive assets with a relatively
small investment. Since past experience
with government investment and lending to the private sector through the
financial institutions suggests that the government would in all probability
play the role of a silent and non-interfering partner, the economic advantages
and power that accrue to the private player as a result of strategic acquisition
are substantial. Such advantages would be all the greater if acquisition of
control through the strategic sale route provides the buyer with a monopolistic
position as has happened in the case of the Reliance acquisition of IPCL. And
the manner in which such power can be misused has come in early, as evidenced by
the effort of the Tata group to use the cash surpluses of VSNL to finance their
own private expansion plans.
ALTERNATIVES
The
point is that despite providing these huge concessions, the evidence from
instances varying from Modern Foods to Balco and more recently the ITDC
properties suggests that disinvestments occurs at prices that are extremely low,
given the worth of or the income earning capacity of the assets that are being
sold. Rather than bend so far as to give the private sector a cheap route to
profit and lose resources of its own in the process, the government could have
adopted other alternatives to find funds for crucial investments. It could, for
example, be argued that if the government wanted to release resources for
investment in the infrastructural sector it could have focused attention on two
areas: First, it could have sold the stake which the financial institutions hold
in a number of private companies in which they have little or no role in actual
management. Rather than have those resources tied up in units which have now
been supported with State funds for long, it makes sense to divest those shares
either to the private promoters or to the market and use the proceeds for other
expenditures. Second, the government can intensify the now virtually
non-existent effort to recover the large volume of resources, estimated at more
than Rs.65000 crore, locked up as non-performing bank assets primarily in large
and medium private sector units.
Unfortunately
the disinvestments controversy does not draw attention to these important
questions, but seeks to stall the process with talk of the need for mid-course
review and correction. This makes the dissenters susceptible to the charge that
they are playing into the hands of particular interests, who want to guard
against the acquisition of these assets by their current or potential
competitors. This also lends credence to those who argue that the
“progressive” policy of disinvestment and reform is being sought to be
derailed by those who have nothing to argue against the policy, but would like
to maintain the status quo in support of traditional vested interests. Those who
have led the campaign against mindless privatisation must expose the controversy
within the NDA on this issue as a charade that diverts attention from and tends
to discredit the real battle against a fraudulent set of policies aimed at
enriching a segment of the private sector at the expense of the State exchequer.