People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXVI
No. 37 September 22,2002 |
VRS - The Voluntary Retirement
Scandal
Jayati Ghosh
DELHI’S
Jawaharlal Nehru University, where I teach, has a branch of the State Bank of
India. It is a small branch, but a very busy one, which caters not just to the
students, teachers and staff of the university, but also to many residents of
the neighbouring areas. But perhaps because of all this, the service was quite
intimate and personal, even if not always spectacularly efficient. The banking
staff knew most of the people who came to the bank, and they generally did their
best to cater to particular requirements. Even when there were delays or huge
crowds, they sought to explain it with apologies.
Last year, the State Bank of India, along with a number of other
nationalized banks, implemented a voluntary retirement scheme for its employees.
A large number of employees actually took advantage of this scheme and sought
premature retirement. In consequence, the overall employment of the State Bank
of India has shrunk. This branch too lost a substantial number of its employees.
The consequences, unfortunately, are only too evident to those who use
the bank. There is now significant understaffing, and consequent overwork of the
remaining employees, with obvious effects on the service. Transactions – even
simple matters such as withdrawing money from an account - which earlier
required a few minutes, can now take up to an hour. There are usually crowds
waiting at each counter, with more waiting time and more mistakes.
The
fault is not that of greater inefficiency of the remaining workers, but that
there are simply not enough people left to do all the required jobs easily and
efficiently. What is worse is that the remaining workers are now not just
overworked but harried and anxious. The same people who earlier would perform
their functions pleasantly and smilingly, are now tense, rushed and even surly,
as they struggle to meet the demands of increasingly irritated customers.
The
bank manager also throws up his hands in despair. He points to the rows of empty
seats, and asks how he can possibly deploy the few remaining people in a way to
ensure that all the customers’ needs are met. If only there had been no VRS,
he muses.
This
story is repeated in branch after branch of various nationalized banks across
the country. But the rot is not confined here. It is even more marked and
evident in the private sector. Recently, two major multinational banks merged,
in an example of growing concentration of the world banking industry. Obviously,
that meant that the banks in India also had to merge. This has entailed the
closing of some branches and the drastic pruning down of staff in others, again
through a Voluntary Retirement Scheme which has focused on getting rid of active
union members.
The
consequence, even in this newly merged multinational bank, is a significant
deterioration in service. Not only have the number of employees dwindled, but
experienced and skilled workers have been replaced with raw recruits who have
yet to learn their work and are prone to many more errors. Many of the bank’s
customers now find it extraordinary that a major bank, which has after all to
ensure great care in the detail of its transactions, is willing to live with
such a situation – all in the name of reducing staff in order to improve
overall efficiency !
These
individual examples point to a much more general tendency, and expose the basic
flaw in much of the reasoning of those who argue that there is overstaffing in
all public sector enterprises, and that workforces can be cut down without any
effect on functioning and productivity. The urban middle classes of our country
somehow seem to have bought this myth, purveyed vigorously by employers and by
neoliberal rightwing economists.
That
is why "downsizing" is supposed to be a good thing, even for essential
public services, and why companies that shed workers are praised rather than
condemned. All too often, it is assumed that the only people to lose in this
process are the workers who lose their jobs. And the policy response then is to
try and set up "safety nets" for such workers.
But
for a whole range of services, both public and private, the consumers of such
services also lose from the process of reducing the number of workers. As the
examples of the banks indicate, there are real losses in terms of delays,
reduced capacity of the remaining workers to cope with the greater load,
resulting mistakes, and a more oppressive atmosphere in the workplace.
In
fact, the only real benefit from such downsizing is usually to be found in the
balance sheets of the companies, as they can show lower labour costs and
therefore possibly higher profits. This is what creates the competitive pressure
across an industry for other companies to follow suit, and to try and reduce the
number of their workers. The current tendency in the banking industry is a
direct reflection of such pressures.
It
is time to call the bluff of those who try and make us believe that downsizing
increases efficiency. Instead, it is really a way of shortchanging both workers
and consumers, and increasing profits at the expense of everyone else. The
irony, of course, is that when all employers try this approach, it leads to
lower economic activity in general, and as a result, for macroeconomic reasons,
profits do not rise either !