People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXVII
No. 30 July 27, 2003 |
Imperialism, Fundamentalism and the
Uses of “Terror”
On
Tuesday, July 18, Dr Jayati Ghosh delivered the 18th A K Gopalan Memorial
Lecture, organised by Jana Sanskriti, at Vithalbhai Patel House, New Delhi. The
first part of the text is being reproduced here. Subheadings have been added.
IT
is an extraordinary honour --- and a privilege --- for me to be invited to
deliver this lecture today. For many people of my generation, Comrade A K
Gopalan was a larger than life figure in many ways, a source of great
inspiration as well as a symbol of all that is best about the communist
movement, expressing the finest qualities of those who struggled in the national
movement and afterwards for a better society. The combination that was embodied
in his life of continuing dedication and commitment, his crucial leadership
qualities, his role in people’s struggles, especially the peasant movement,
his simplicity and approachability, remains a model worthy of emulation.
Especially in the current context, when some degree of cynicism seems to pervade
the atmosphere, even among the young, his consistent idealism is important to
remember.
In
this lecture I would like to take up some of the issues that were central to the
political activism of Comrade AKG himself, which have acquired a particular
urgency today.
Two
features of the capitalist world economy in the early years of the new century
must be noted at the outset. The first is the continuing, indeed overwhelming,
significance of imperialism as the defining feature of global economic
relations, with imperialism broadly defined as the struggle by large capital for
control over economic territory of various types. The second is that this
current imperialism is different in several crucial ways from that described by
Lenin nearly a century ago as the monopoly stage of capitalism. To some extent
the differences are simply the result of history, the evolution of both the
institutions and processes of capitalism. But they are also the result of the
effects of the recent processes of deregulation of trade and capital markets as
well as other forms of economic liberalisation (constituting the essence of what
is typically called “globalisation”), which have given the new imperialism
its cutting edge.
IMPORTANT
DIFFERENCES
In
terms of the current world economy, a number of important differences from the
imperialist globalisation of the late 19th century can be identified. These
include:
1)
the implications of accentuated internationalisation and concentration of both
production and finance;
2)
the greater domination and changed nature of finance capital;
3)
the use of multilateral institutions and rule-based regimes to further the aims
that in earlier periods of history were resolved through more direct
militaristic or political means;
4)
the changed nature of the systemic instability of global capitalism;
5)
the new forms of economic territory that are currently being contested, as well
as the creation of new markets;
6)
technological changes that have furthered the process of global corporate
dominance as well as allowed for the possibility of confronting it at an
international level;
7)
the implications of the global spread, privatisation and concentration of media
industries;
8)
the current submergence of inter-imperialist rivalry in the face of a sole
superpower whose military might is increasingly being systematically used to
perpetuate dominance. I have earlier referred to this as
“hyper-imperialism,” with the US taking on more and more powers and
disregarding international institutions whenever it chooses to do so.
It
is obvious that the processes of concentration and centralisation of capital, as
well as the internationalisation of production, have gone much further, with
some important implications. The recent phase of globalisation has been marked
by some of the strongest and most sweeping waves of concentration of economic
activity that we have known historically. In terms of multinational firms’
activities, the possibility of vertical disintegration of production, which has
allowed parts of the production process to be relocated and geographically
separated, has been associated with greater vertical integration of the control
(and ownership) of production internationally. In addition, the past decade in
particular has witnessed a wave of cross-border mergers and acquisitions across
not only major manufacturing industries but even in the services sector and in
utility provision. The increased concentration of economic activity in general
could reflect the recession and slump in recent years: concentration is always
more marked in the downswing phase of economic cycles. But the process is also
evident in some of the more “dynamic” sectors, such as telecom, the media
and entertainment industries, and even during the expansionary phases of such
sectors. This process should not, however, be misinterpreted to imply that the
links between multinational conglomerates and their home governments have
disappeared: they may appear to be more tenuous, but nevertheless still exist
and continue to influence geo-political and economic strategies of the major
capitalist powers.
IMPLICATIONS OF THE PROCESSES
Internationalisation
is, of course, most marked for finance. The domination of financial flows in
cross-border transactions, as well as the greater role played by speculative
elements and the separation (and to some extent supremacy) of finance capital
over productive capital, are too well known to require further discussion.
However, some of the more significant implications of these processes may be
noted. They include:
1)
the enhanced differentials in speeds of adjustment between capital markets and
the markets for goods and services, implying both more rapid changes in terms of
financial variables and more accentuated effects on real economies;
2)
the destabilising role played by speculative capital flows, leading to more
volatility of relative prices in general and periodic crises of varying
intensity in particular economies;
3)
the constraints on, and deflationary impetus imparted to, national economic
policy making, especially fiscal and monetary policies in almost all countries,
and the heightened inability of states (independent of political persuasion) to
ensure basic needs and minimum socio-economic rights to all citizens;
4)
the necessity on the part of finance for constantly (if temporarily) discovering
new avenues (or emerging markets) for investment, which ensures that deflation
is not a uniform process across the world economy, but is always accompanied by
a few pockets of capital-inflow-led boom.
The
domination of finance capital has had effects on the nature of inter-imperialist
rivalry as well. The point is essentially as follows: when finance capital,
independent of national origin, seeks to ensure the stability of its
investments, then it will be especially concerned about some degree of stability
at the capitalist core, notably in US government and private securities. This
means that (notwithstanding the recent and continuing decline of US stock
markets, the revulsion away from US financial assets and the associated decline
of the US dollar in world currency markets) there will be attempts to maintain
some degree of stability in terms of the most important financial assets
available, and therefore to reinforce the geopolitical arrangements which
underlie such stability. This requirement creates a different source of pressure
from that determined solely by US military domination. It means that in crucial
political and economic areas, the important capitalist powers tend to act
together or at least implicitly endorse the positions taken by the US, whether
in the WTO negotiations or in the use of the IMF, to determine country policies
to directly or indirectly benefit US-based capital, or in the “war on
terror,” and treatment of so-called “rogue states,” and so on. It also
means that US unilateralism in economic and political matters tends to be
accepted (if not condoned), whether in terms of allowing the continued use of
unilateral protectionist measures such as Super 301 etc, or the US Farm Bill, or
in terms of pushing for greater enforcement of multilateral liberalisation in
precisely those sectors in which the US economy is perceived to have competitive
advantage, or in terms of military engagements with what it chooses to define as
“rogue states,” or even, now, of illegal occupation of another country along
neo-colonial lines.
It
is worth noting that the new imperialism, in addition to utilising new
institutions and international rules and protocols to its own end, is also about
the struggle to control newer forms of economic territory. This is not to deny
the continuing significance of economic territory as traditionally conceived,
that is natural resources, markets and labour. Indeed, control over natural
resources --- particularly energy and oil resources --- remains central to
imperialist preoccupation. This is demonstrated by a number of recent and
current events: the significance of the proposed (and soon to be constructed)
oil pipeline in Afghanistan to the US military intervention and ongoing
geopolitics of the region; the (failed) attempt to instigate and support a
military coup in Venezuela against a president elected by a huge popular margin.
The war on Iraq, and its subsequent occupation, is simply the latest
manifestation of this. While these are in fact the most blatant political
expressions of imperialism today, it is in the area of developing new markets
that the economic implications are most pronounced.
SEEKING
TO DEVELOP NEW
MARKETS
These
new markets are sought to be developed and made accessible in two ways. The
first is the opening up of existing markets in developing and formerly socialist
countries through the processes of trade and investment liberalisation, using
the agencies of conditional lending by the IMF and World Bank and more recently,
the rules and dispute settlement procedures of the WTO. Such opening up,
especially if it involves the relative deindustrialisation of the newly
liberalised economies, contributes new markets for manufactured goods and
services for the core capitalist countries. It is surely not an accident that,
despite fears of manufacturing jobs being “exported” from North to South, in
fact the manufacturing trade balance of the South with the North remains
negative and indeed the deficit has been growing. Associated with this is the
lowering of world prices of Southern exports, which stems from the fallacy of
composition problem, as more and more developing countries are forced to
increase export volumes either to repay debt, or to pay for more imports, or
simply because they have been told that it is good for them to do so. This is
turn provides the related advantage of cheaper imports to the core countries,
not only of raw materials and tropical agricultural commodities, but also of the
manufactured goods which developing countries have been encouraged to specialise
in and which are now characterised by massive over-capacity internationally.
The
more innovative form of finding new markets in the recent past has been that of
creating markets where none previously existed, that is, by encouraging and
furthering the commercialisation of activities that were earlier not perceived
as commercial, or were defined in the public domain, or were only enabled by
social intervention. The push towards commercialisation and then privatisation
of a range of public services --- such as power, telecommunication, and now
water and sanitation --- is the most obvious expression of this. The
proliferation of new forms of commerce has never been so rampant. Knowledge and
what is defined as intellectual property, rights to energy use, pollution
control certificates, all are now subject to trading; even the via media for
trade have expanded to include e-commerce and the like. The forced
commercialisation of a wide range of services therefore provides the newest and
most promising hinterland for capitalist expansion.
One
aspect of this is also that information and entertainment have themselves become
not just commercialised but have emerged as major industries; indeed, they are
now the fastest growing segments of the global economy. They are also among the
most concentrated and centralised of all sectors. The multimedia boom has
spawned large multimedia companies who can now be counted among the largest
multinational corporations. This is really a phenomenon of the last decade, or
of at most the last 15 years or so, as giant media firms have sought
"synergy" through not just vertical integration but by effectively
"acquiring control of every step in the mass media process, from creation
of content to its delivery in the home." The 1990s witnessed an
unprecedented wave of mergers and acquisitions among global media giants. (As a
result, the top six multinational conglomerates --- News Corporation, Time
Warner, Disney, Bertelsmann, Viacom and TCI --- now effectively own and control
huge swathes of the media, publishing and commercial entertainment activities
across the world.) Many of these firms have explicitly
rejected national identities and posited themselves as global or internationally
based corporations. Nevertheless, and despite the attempts to programme
according to local sensibilities, the bulk of the content, the forms of
expression and the structures of ownership and management reflect the domination
of the core capitalist countries, especially the US.
In
sheer quantitative terms, the most important new markets are of course the
financial ones, and the explosion of financial activity reflects the ability of
capitalism to create and enlarge the spheres of economic activity even where
material production is flagging. In addition, financial services such as banking
and insurance --- an area in which companies based in the core capitalist
countries clearly have competitive advantage --- have been among the fastest
growing areas of world trade. The huge cross-border and intra-border flow of
financial resources often reflects trade in commodities which are purely
notional, such as derivatives trading. That huge profits can be made from this
pyramiding of financial assets reflects the ingenuity of capitalism, but it also
marks speculative bubbles, which do have to burst eventually.
In
addition, the new imperialism seeks to make use of particularly the skilled
labour to be found in some developing countries. This has meant greatly enhanced
labour mobility of a small section of highly skilled and professional employees,
even as other labour finds it much more difficult to move, and aggregate rates
of labour migration are lower than they have been in the history of capitalism.
This in turn has contributed in no small measure to the enthusiasm for the
process of global integration among such groups of skilled workers in developing
countries. In fact, it can be argued that one important reason for the success
of imperialist globalisation has been its ability to draw local elites and
middle classes across the world into its own ranks, to offer part inclusion into
a privileged international space within which the travails of the local working
poor can be forgotten, even while their crucial role in generating productive
surplus is sustained.
INSTABILITY
OF WORLD
Despite
the appearance of complete domination by a single and determined superpower,
which has been a requirement for period of stable world capitalism in the past,
the current world economy is an unstable one, which is prone to systemic
instability and constant possibility of crisis. This emerges from the following
factors.
First,
the US is not currently fulfilling its role (in the Kindleberger sense) of
leader in the world economy to maintain stability. Such a role requires the
fulfilment of three functions at a minimum: discounting in crisis;
counter-cyclical lending to countries affected by private investors’
decisions; and providing a market for net exports of the rest of the world,
especially those countries requiring it to repay debt. The absence of
discounting in crisis is not universal; there are countries that have received
large bailouts orchestrated by the US Treasury and the IMF. But the spectacular
collapse of Argentina, the bleeding of Sub-Saharan Africa despite impending
large-scale famine, and the indifference to implosions in Eastern Europe and
elsewhere, bear witness to the fact that the US administration does not see its
responsibility to discount in crisis in terms of salvaging the larger system.
Similarly, counter-cyclical lending has been discouraged, as private finance
(including portfolio capital) has been associated with creating sharp
boom-and-bust cycles rather than mitigating them, and US policy has been geared
towards protecting such behaviour rather than repressing it. Finally, while the
US did play a crucial role as engine of world trade by running very large
external trade deficits in the 1990s, that role has been much diminished after
2000. Indeed, even before then, the import surplus in the US reflected private
investment-savings deficits, as the government’s budgetary role became more
contractionary.
Second,
partly because of this inadequately accepted role of the leader, and partly
because of the deflationary impulse provided by the greater mobility of finance
capital, aggregate growth in the world capitalist system has been far below
expectations in the recent phase of globalisation. It is now clear that the
period has been associated with a deceleration of economic activity in much of
the developed world, a continuing implosion in vast areas of the developing
world including the continent of Africa, and a dramatic downslide in what had
hitherto been the most dynamic segment of the world economy --- East and South
East Asia. (Global output growth, which averaged 3 per cent in the period
1990-97, was less than half that rate in 1998-2000, and even worse subsequently.
Nearly 40 developing countries have experienced declines in per capita income
since 1990.) These processes
are reflected in rates of growth of world trade (in value terms), which have
decelerated despite the enforced liberalisation of trade in most countries, as
well as in declining rates of greenfield investment across the world.
Third,
the recent process of imperialist globalisation has been marked by greatly
increased disparities, both within countries and between countries. (The
gap in per capita income between industrial and developing worlds has more than
tripled between the 1960 and 1990. Between 1960 and 1991, the income share of
the richest 20 per cent of the world's population rose from 70 per cent to 85
per cent, while the income share of the poorest 20 per cent of population fell
from 2.3 per cent to 1.4 per cent. In fact, the income shares of more than 85
per cent of the world's population actually fell over this period. The ratio of
shares of the richest to the poorest groups doubled from 30:1 to 60:1.
Subsequent data indicate a marked worsening of such disparities.)
While there is --- inevitably --- a debate over this, most careful studies find
increased inequality within and across regions as well as a stubborn persistence
of poverty, and a marked absence of the “convergence” predicted by
apologists of the system. In addition, the bulk of the people across the world
find themselves in more fragile and vulnerable economic circumstances, in which
many of the earlier welfare state provisions have been reduced or removed,
public services have been privatised or made more expensive and therefore less
accessible, and employment conditions have become much more insecure and
volatile.
Fourth,
these features in themselves have led to a major crisis of legitimisation for
the system. Not only are the basic tenets of the neo-liberal argument (which
forms the theoretical support for the current pattern of imperialist
globalisation) under question, but increasingly the institutions which serve to
uphold it (the IMF, the WTO and so on) lack popular support and legitimacy. The
anti-globalisation umbrella movement is one expression of such growing dissent
in local and national contexts. One important --- and new --- feature, is that
the process of integrating elites from developing countries, and rewarding them
materially for their active cooperation in furthering corporate globalisation,
has slowed down. As argued above, the complicity and participation of local
elites has been a potent force in ensuring the success of global capitalist
integration --- but as the world recession bites and rewards become more scarce,
such complicity can no longer be taken for granted. Since the political economy
of resistance movements everywhere requires the involvement of at least some
middle class and professional elements and often some local elites as well, this
may prove to be a critical development.
Fifth,
imperialism has an increasingly ambiguous relationship with various backward
looking, revanchist and reactionary tendencies in different parts of the world.
At different times and places, such tendencies have been encouraged and allowed
to spread, but increasingly many of them are now seen as threats to the system,
to be rooted out and destroyed. All of those currently seen as enemies of the US
and therefore as the objects of attrition in the current “war against
terror” --- Osama bin Laden, Al
Qaeda and the Taliban, Saddam Hussein --- have been at one time or the other
overt or covert darlings of the US administration, used against other perceived
enemies or simply to destabilise regions. Even now, in clientelist regimes such
as that in Saudi Arabia, reactionary forces have been allowed to grow.
Elsewhere, US imperialism has turned a blind eye or even implicitly encouraged
the growth of semi-fascist movements (such as the Hindutva tendencies in India)
as well as separatist forces, which encourage the disintegration of large
nations. However, many of these movements now threaten to spin out of control
and to destabilise the system itself, even if only partially. The terrorist
attacks of September 2001 mark a watershed only, insofar as they forced a
realisation of this tendency towards destabilisation; they do not mark any major
changes in basic organisation of the system itself, which is still run as
cynically as before.
Finally,
one important contradiction looks likely to become more significant in the near
future. This is the requirement of deflation, which predatory finance capital
imposes on the system as a whole even while it encourages differential rates of
deflation in different areas so as to maximise its own profits. A sustainable
prey-predator relation requires the continued existence of the prey, but
widespread deflation makes this less likely. The current downslide in the major
equity markets, and especially in the US, suggests that while finance can be
separated from real economic trends for extended periods, and can even profit by
such separation, it cannot do so indefinitely.
All
this means that, while the world capitalist system may not yet be in
full-fledged crisis (even though parts of it clearly are), there are systemic
instabilities which suggest that the current pattern cannot continue without
some changes or even substantial overhaul in the medium term.
(To
Be Concluded)