People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXIX
No. 06 February 06, 2005 |
The
Future Of The WTO
TRADE
LIBERALISATION
Developing
countries in particular feel that they have been short-changed, forced into
trade liberalisation patterns that have had de-industrialising effects and
created agrarian crises, even as the promised benefits of increased market
access in agricultural commodities and textiles have been denied them. The
spirit of the Agreement on Agriculture and the Agreement on Textiles have
clothing have been breached not only in the small print of these agreements but
in the implementation. Developing country governments also feel increasingly
hemmed in and their citizens feel exploited, by the range of new rules that
affect non-trade policies within the country, including those relating to
intellectual property.
Meanwhile,
even developed countries are less than enthusiastic about the multilateral
process, which makes complete domination difficult and does not allow for even
more aggressive opening up of markets of other countries. The
Unites States in particular has for some time treated WTO rules and decisions
with a degree of contempt when these do not suit its government, even while it
had used it as an instrument of pushing for trade liberalisation in its favour.
Both the US and the EU are also voting with their hands, so to speak: signing a
plethora of bilateral and regional trade agreements outside the scope of the WTO,
such that such deals now cover more than 70 per cent of world trade.
What
is even more compromising to the early proponents of the Uruguay Round, is that the most massive trade
liberalisation the world economy has ever experienced has been accompanied by no
commensurate increase in trade flows.
Both Table 1 and Chart 1 indicate the annual rate of change in world trade in
volume terms as well as in nominal (US dollar) values. It
is immediately evident that in the period after the signing of the Uruguay Round
agreement and the formation of the WTO (that is, 1995 onwards) world trade
experienced no greater trend of growth and possibly even greater volatility,
compared to the previous decade.
Table
1
|
|||||
World
trade rate of change (per cent) |
|||||
Year |
Value |
Volume |
Year |
Value |
Volume |
1984 |
8.1 |
10.8 |
1994 |
15.6 |
11.1 |
1985 |
3.8 |
4.8 |
1995 |
20.0 |
9.0 |
1986 |
20.3 |
4.1 |
1996 |
3.5 |
5.3 |
1987 |
19.7 |
6.3 |
1997 |
4.6 |
11.0 |
1988 |
16.1 |
9.5 |
1998 |
2.3 |
4.8 |
1989 |
6.9 |
7.8 |
1999 |
3.3 |
5.1 |
1990 |
14.7 |
6.1 |
2000 |
10.2 |
13.0 |
1991 |
3.3 |
3.6 |
2001 |
-3.8 |
-1.2 |
1992 |
8.0 |
4.7 |
2002 |
5.2 |
3.9 |
1993 |
0.0 |
4.1 |
2003 |
14.5 |
4.8 |
AVOIDING
DEMOCRATIC DECISION MAKING
In
addition, the functioning of the WTO itself has come in for severe criticism.
Two of the Ministerial Meetings – at Seattle and then at Cancun – failed to
come to any agreement at least partly because of developing country members’
disgust at the heavy handed manner in which the secretariat sought to impose its
will (largely reflecting US-EU positions), influence the discussions and avoid
democratic decision-making. The infamous “Green Room” discussions of WTO
negotiations, in which small groups of developing countries have been
“persuaded” or forced to accept decisions they had initially opposed, have
been exposed by Aileen Kwa and others. Even the Dispute Settlement procedures
have become another hurdle especially for small developing countries who find
them extremely expensive, cumbersome and unduly prolonged.
Clearly
there is much to reform in both the process of negotiations and in the
functioning of the WTO. In this context, it is not surprising, and it is
certainly desirable, that the WTO itself instituted a special commission to look
into these matters, focus on institutional issues, and provide recommendations
to reform the way the organisation works and how decisions are made. This
represented a tremendous opportunity to address some of the most glaring
problems and try to reform the WTO in ways that would give it at least a minimal
degree of legitimacy among the people of the world.
LOST OPPORTUNITY
Sadly,
however, this opportunity has been squandered. The report of the Commission thus
set up (The Future of the WTO,
Geneva: WTO, 2005) is no more than a rather weak justification and defence not
only of the entire set of principles on which the trade negotiations have been
based, but also of the clearly problematic workings of the WTO. There is not
even an attempt at cosmetic repair; rather, the existing unsatisfactory system,
warts and all, is held up as a model to be further pushed.
This
may be related to the composition of the Commission, which is headed by Peter
Sutherland, the first director-general of the WTO and presently chairman of two
major international conglomerates of finance and industry: Goldman Sachs
International and British Petroleum. It also includes among its eight members
the most vociferous advocate of free trade, the Indian economist Jagdish
Bhagwati.
COMPLETE
MISREPRESENTATION
At
any rate, the Report disappoints because it treats all the concerns and
criticisms of the functioning of the WTO merely as so many debating points,
without any serious attempt to evaluate the genuine need for reform. Therefore
the proposals it provides are so lacking in imagination that they simply
advocate doing more of the same, and more aggressively than before. Where the
functioning of the WTO and the negotiation process have been undemocratic and
non-transparent, it actually suggests formalising these features rather than
changing them.
The
basic assumptions of the Commission are clearly laid out in the opening
chapters. It is an axiom for the Commission that trade does inspire growth and
growth will combat poverty. This is accepted so uncritically that the evidence
on recent deindustrialisation and associated lack of employment in developing
countries is simply not considered: all this is simply blamed upon technological
progress.
Within
this, the WTO is seen as a force only to the good. “The
WTO provides a level playing field with a credible referee dealing even-handedly
with the players”. (page
15) What would subsistence peasants in central America, whose cultivation has
been rendered unviable by cheap imports of highly subsidised maize sold by giant
US corporations, make of this? Or the millions of small producers across the
world whose livelihood has been wiped out by import competition driven by large
companies?
Similarly,
“the WTO constrains the powerful”
(page 18). No doubt that is why the share of MNCs in global trade has increased
dramatically over the past decade, and concentration in all major spheres of
economic activity has accelerated greatly. In any case, any shortcomings are not
because of the WTO system but because individual member countries are unable to
avail of the manifold benefits: “The
WTO is about providing opportunities – it does not provide guarantees nor does
it provide all the conditions for participation in the global economy.” So
if people are suffering as a result of trade liberalisation and increased
patent-based monopolies, it is their own fault.
In
any case, the Commission clearly feels that enough time and energy has already
been spent on dealing with all the carping from the world’s poor and on weaker
member countries. “The time
and effort that has been expended in recent years in the WTO and associated
agencies in addressing the needs and handicaps of the world’s smallest and
poorest countries in the trading system is remarkable, by any standards.”
(page 17)
Another
concern of member countries, that WTO rules are increasingly interfering in
domestic economies and constraining the policy autonomy of governments, is given
short shrift. According to the Commission, “in the context of the WTO, the
complaint over sovereignty is a red herring” (page 29) and is in any case
misplaced because governments can now apparently “reclaim control at the
multilateral level”. (page 34). Which governments can really do so, and how,
are questions that are conveniently left unanswered.
With
such a framework, the conclusions and recommendations of the Commission,
alarming as they are, come as no real surprise. The
Report condemns preferential trade agreements (PTAs) – except, naturally, the
European Union and NAFTA, which are supposed to be all right because they
apparently encourage a more positive attitude to multilateralism!
The PTAs of developing countries, by contrast, such as Mercosur, are seen as
undesirable because they only involve trade diversion and are somehow different
from the NAFTA and EU in becoming stumbling blocks to the multilateral process.
Special
and Differential Treatment (S&DT) for developing countries in WTO comes in
for even sharper criticism. The Report argues that this has been based on two
assumptions: first, that demands for reciprocal concessions from developing
countries are inappropriate because of the different effects of trade
liberalisation; and second, that in any case the markets of developing countries
are so small as to be insignificant and so concession do not really matter. The
Report argues that neither of these assumptions is valid, since developing
country markets have grown and because it sees a strong case for the benefits of
trade liberalisation in all cases.
In
consequence, the Commission finds too many “fault lines” in S&DT. While
the Report does not go so far as to suggest the complete removal of S&DT, it
does suggest that “these mechanisms require further study and research”
(page 24). Even the Generalised System of Preferences (GSP) for developing
country exports, which have played such a role in encouraging some basic
industrialisation in developing countries, are dismissed as having had little
positive effect.
The
combination of preferential trade agreements, S&DT and GSP is seen to have
created a “spaghetti bowl” of discriminatory preferences that is clearly
anathema to the simplicity beloved of the Commission. So they advocate reducing
all most-favoured nation tariffs to zero, which would clearly eliminate the
spaghetti bowl problem!
Note that quite apart from anything else, this approach is extremely unfair to
developing countries where tariffs remain the dominant form of protection,
unlike developed countries where non-tariff barriers now dominate. Given the
havoc already created in the production systems of the South through the trade
liberalisation experienced so far, this proposal is breath-taking in its
ignorance of reality.
COMMISSION’S
RECOMMENDATIONS
Some
of the most important recommendations relate to the functioning of the WTO and
the entire process of trade negotiation, about which there has been much valid
criticism. Clearly, the Commission is unhappy with even the veneer of democracy
that is currently maintained in the WTO. The consensus approach is obviously
preferred over voting (which would give developing country member a majority),
but the problem with consensus building is that “the majority’s will can be
blocked by even one country”.
In
fact, the Report ends up
advocating instead the plurilateralist approach which was already suggested by
the EU and has already been rejected by developing countries. Here it has been
renamed “variable geometry approach”, but it still involves “opt-in” and
“opt-out” possibilities such that some members may choose to take on more
obligations.
Also,
the Commission is clearly impatient with the slow progress of negotiations, and
wants to speed them up by increasing the strong arm tactics already availed of
by the large member countries and the WTO secretariat. The Report argues that “Green
Room” meetings with limited access are both appropriate and necessary,
notwithstanding their undemocratic nature.
It
also argues that the “member-driven” nature of the WTO has involved a
reduction in the role of the Secretariat, and instead proposes a much-enhanced
role for this body. It should be noted that the Secretariat is an appointed body
with no accountability, and its activities in the past have indicated a clear
bias towards the positions of the large developed countries. Despite this (or
perhaps because of this?) the
Report advocates a leading role for the Secretariat at Ministerial Meetings.
Instead of allowing for election of Chairs and facilitators of meetings, the
Commission wants these to be pre-announced by the Secretariat, and argues that
these appointments “should not become part of a further bargaining process.”
The
remarkable thing about the Report is that it calls for an intensification of all
the processes and procedures in the WTO that have been identified by developing
country members as part of the problem. The
continuation and even acceleration of indiscriminate trade liberalisation
without concern for its impact on employment and economic activity, no controls
on unilateralism by the strong members especially the US, no protection from the
monopolies created by the workings of the TRIPS agreement – all form part of
the recommendations of the Commission. And in addition, it calls for formalising
the unequal and undemocratic manner of functioning of the WTO.
Despite
its claims to be an independent Commission, this is clearly a report by and for
the WTO Secretariat. Rather than increasing its international credibility, it is
likely to diminish it further.