People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXX
No. 14 April 02, 2006 |
Amitayu Sen Gupta
Shouvik Chakraborty
ON
the inaugural function of the 16th Asian Corporate Conference (March 18, 2006),
the prime minister Dr Manmohan Singh, stated that there is merit in India’s
moving forward towards fuller Capital Account Convertibility. In an immediate
response, the RBI set up a committee under the Chairmanship of Mr S S Tarapore
to pave the way for the Capital Account Convertibility. This article provides a
basic analysis of the problems involved with the issue of Capital Account
Convertibility in India.
WHAT IS CAC?
In
India, the foreign exchange transactions (transactions in dollars, pounds, or
any other currency) are broadly classified into two accounts: current
account transactions and capital
account transactions. If an Indian citizen needs foreign exchange of smaller
amounts, say $3,000, for travelling abroad or for educational purposes, she/he
can obtain the same from a bank or a money-changer. This is a “current
account transaction”. But, if someone wants to import plant and
machinery or invest abroad, and needs a large amount of foreign exchange, say $1
million, the importer will have to first obtain the permission of the Reserve
Bank of India (RBI). If approved, this becomes a “capital
account transaction”. This means that any domestic or foreign investor
has to seek the permission from a regulatory authority, like the RBI, before
carrying out any financial transactions or change of ownership of assets that
comes under the capital account. Of course there are a whole range of financial
transactions on the capital account that may be freed form such restrictions, as
is the case in India today. But this is still not the same as full capital account convertibility.
By
“Capital Account Convertibility”
(or CAC in short), we mean “the freedom to convert the local financial
assets into foreign financial assets and vice-versa at market determined rates
of exchange. It is associated with the changes of ownership in foreign/domestic
financial assets and liabilities and embodies the creation and liquidation of
claims on, or by the rest of the world. …” (Report of the Committee
on Capital Account Convertibility, RBI, 1997) Thus, in simpler terms, it means
that irrespective of whether one is a resident or non-resident of India one’s
assets and liabilities can be freely (i.e. without permission of any regulatory
authority) denominated (or cashed) in any currency and easily interchanged
between that currency and the Rupee.
PROBLEMS WITH CAC
Several
economists are of the view that the full Capital Account Convertibility (and
allowing the exchange rate to be market determined) has serious consequences on
the wellbeing of the country, and this may even lead to extreme sufferings of
the common masses. Some of the reasons are highlighted below.
During
the good years of the economy, it might experience huge inflows of foreign
capital, but during the bad times there will be an enormous outflow of
capital under “herd behaviour” (refers to a phenomenon where
investors acts as “herds”, i.e. if one moves out, others follow
immediately). For example, the South East Asian countries received US$ 94
billion in 1996 and another US$ 70 billion in the first half of 1997.
However, under the threat of the crisis, US$ 102 billion flowed out from the
region in the second half of 1997, thereby accentuating the crisis. This has
serious impact on the economy as a whole, and can even lead to an economic
crisis as in South-East Asia.
There
arises the possibility of misallocation of capital inflows.
Such capital inflows may fund low-quality domestic investments, like
investments in the stock markets or real estates, and desist from investing
in building up industries and factories, which leads to more capacity
creation and utilisation, and increased level of employment. This also
reduces the potential of the country to increase exports and thus creates
external imbalances.
An
open capital account can lead to “the export of domestic savings”
(the rich can convert their savings into dollars or pounds in foreign banks
or even assets in foreign countries), which for capital scarce developing
countries would curb domestic investment. Moreover, under the threat of a
crisis, the domestic savings too might leave the country along with the
foreign ‘investments’, thereby rendering the government helpless to
counter the threat.
Entry
of foreign banks can create an unequal playing field, whereby
foreign banks “cherry-pick” the most creditworthy borrowers and
depositors. This aggravates the problem of the farmers and the small-scale
industrialists, who are not considered to be credit-worthy by these banks.
In order to remain competitive, the domestic banks too refuse to lend to
these sectors, or demand to raise interest rates to more “competitive”
levels from the ‘subsidised’ rates usually followed.
International
finance capital today is “highly volatile”,
i.e. it shifts from country to country in search of higher speculative
returns. In this process, it has led to economic crisis in numerous
developing countries. Such finance capital is referred to as “hot money” in today’s context. Full capital account
convertibility exposes an economy to extreme volatility on account of “hot
money” flows.
According
to Joseph Stiglitz, the former Chief
Economist at the World Bank and a Nobel Laureate in 2001,
“Capital
market liberalization entails stripping away the regulations intended to control
the flow of hot money in and out of the country- short term loans and contracts
that are usually no more than bets on exchange rate movements. This speculative
money cannot be used to build factories or create jobs- companies don’t make
long term investments using money that can be pulled out on a moment’s notice-
and indeed, the risk that such hot money brings with it makes long-term
investments in a developing country even less attractive.”-
(Globalisation and its’ Discontents, 2002.)
EXPERIENCES OF DEVELOPING COUNTRIES WITH CAC
Over
the past two decades, under the diktat of the IMF-World Bank, several developing
countries have undertaken measures to open their capital account as part of a
broader process of financial liberalisation and international economic
integration. Several developing countries like Argentina, Kenya, Mexico and the
South East Asia (Indonesia, South Korea, Malaysia and Thailand) liberalized
their capital accounts over the last few years.
The
early 1990s experienced a boom in capital flows internationally followed by the
reversal of such flows especially in the second half of the 1990s. The first
reversal occurred in the aftermath of Mexico’s currency crisis in December
1994. It was, however, limited to some Latin American economies and capital
flows resumed soon after. The second reversal, which was more severe and
enduring, came in 1997 and resulted in the East Asian crisis. This was followed
by the Russian default in August 1998 and the Brazilian crisis in 1998-99,
followed more recently by the collapse of the Argentine currency in 2001 and the
spate of corporate failures and accounting irregularities in the USA in 2002.
Needless to say, all the developing countries faced major crisis due to such
vagaries of finance capital, whereas the only gainers were the handful of
financers who control the flows of such capital.
But,
these crises did not affect the Indian economy since India had regulations on
capital account. Even a conservative economist like Jagadish
Bhagwati recognized this point when he argued that “It is noteworthy
that both India and China escaped the Asian Financial crisis; (since) they did
not have Capital Account Convertibility.” – (US House of
Representatives Committee on Financial Services, April, 2003).
WHO BENEFITS FROM “CAC”?
The
class which benefits from the CAC primarily compromises the big business houses
and the finance capitalists, who invest in the stock market for speculations.
The policies like
CAC are pursued mainly to gain the confidence of the speculators and punters in
the Stock Markets, and do not have any beneficial effects on the real sector of
the economy, like increasing the employment level, eliminating poverty and
decreasing the inequality gap. However, the irony is that under a crisis, the
burden is borne primarily by the common masses. This may come in the form of a
sharper reduction in subsidies, less investment for social welfare projects by
the government and an increase in the privatisation process. The foreign
speculators and the domestic players may walk out of the market (by converting
their assets to foreign currency) and insulate themselves from any damage.
By
August 1994, India was forced to adopt full current account convertibility under
the obligations of IMF’s article of agreement (Article No. VII). The committee
on Capital Account Convertibility, under Dr S S Tarapore’s chairmanship,
submitted its report in May 1997 and observed that international
experience showed that a more open capital account could impose tremendous
pressures on the financial system. Hence, the committee recommended
certain signposts or preconditions for Capital Account Convertibility in India.
However, the agenda of Capital Account Convertibility was put on hold following
the South-East Asian crisis. Even the finance minister acknowledged this point
that “...the idea of Capital Account Convertibility was floated in 1997
by the Tarapore Committee, but could not be implemented as the Asian Crisis
cropped up”. (The Hindu, March 25, 2006). The RBI over a period
of time has accepted the point that the South East Asian crisis was a bad
example for Capital Account Convertibility and that India had been insulated
from the crisis because it had not allowed Capital Account Convertibility.
“The
growing global macroeconomic imbalance – as evidenced by the large and
sustained current account deficit of the US – suggests that markets may at
times allocate global saving differently from what is perceived by the policy
makers as appropriate and sustainable in the long-run. Like the effect on
resource allocation, the beneficial effects of capital account liberalisation on
growth are ambiguous.”
– (Report
on Currency and Finance 2002-03, RBI.)
But
at the same time, the RBI had started talking about Capital Account relaxations,
under pressure from the business classes in India. However, given the obvious
pitfalls of CAC policies, the RBI talked about a cautious approach to CAC.
“In
India, it is recognised that the pace of liberalisation of the capital account
would depend on both domestic factors (especially progress in the financial
sector reform), and the evolving international financial architecture. The
regulatory framework is being used in several combinations to address problems
of excessive inflows and pressures towards outflows.
In this regard, an integrated view of the state of development of
activities in financial markets needs to be taken.”
-
(Report
on Currency and Finance 2002-03, RBI.)
It is interesting to note here that there already exists a great amount of freedom in transacting foreign currencies today:
Indian
residents and companies (listed in the share markets) can invest in foreign
companies, provided a) the foreign company has 10 per cent share holding in
some Indian company and b) the domestic country does not invest an amount
more than 25 per cent of the company’s total valuation. However, if an
Indian company has a “proven track record” it can invest an amount up to
100 per cent of its total valuation in a foreign entity engaged in a
“bonafide” business activity.
There
is no monetary limit on such aforesaid investments by individuals.
Indian
banks can invest their “unutilised” FCNR(B) funds (Foreign
Currency (Non-Resident) Accounts (Banks)- accounts in
which NRI’s and PIO’s can deposit in any Indian bank) abroad
in only long term fixed income securities which have some minimum ratings
(read credibility) internationally.
An
Indian exporter can give “loans” out of its foreign earnings to foreign
importers without any limit; i.e. the foreign exchange earned need not
necessarily be deposited in the country.
Indians
can have Residents Foreign Currency (domestic) Accounts in which they can
hold their savings in foreign currency without any limit. They can also
remit these foreign currencies to acquire foreign securities (from foreign
stock markets) under Employees Stock Option Plan (ESOP) without any limits.
NRI,
PIO and non residents can take up to US$1 million per year out of the
country from balances held in Non Resident Ordinary (NRO) accounts/ sales of
Indian assets. Such assets may include those acquired through
inheritance/legacy.
Any
further relaxations would render the Indian economy susceptible to the kind of
crisis faced by the other developing countries.
Why
then is the government interested in introducing Capital Account Convertibility?
The
UPA government, since its inception, had has been pursuing the policies of
liberalistion and privatisation, which underscore its commitment to
neo-liberalism. Notwithstanding certain policy announcements in the NCMP, the
government is unwilling to change course and is in essence pursuing the same
policies as the NDA. A policy like Capital Account Convertibility is a
reflection of this. Such policies solely benefit the rich business houses,
investors in the stock markets and those who control the international finance
markets. The prime minister and the finance minister are more than eager to
serve the vested interests of these classes.
Dani
Rodrik,
an eminent Harvard economist, has argued that
“The
greatest concern I have about canonizing capital-account convertibility is that
it will leave economic policy in the typical “emerging market” hostage to
the whims and fancies of two dozen or so thirty-something country analysts in
London, Frankfurt, and New York. A finance minister whose top priority is to
keep foreign investors happy will be one who pays less attention to
developmental goals. We would have to have blind faith in the efficiency and
rationality of international capital markets to believe that these two sets of
priorities will regularly coincide.”--- (“Who
Needs Capital Account Convertibility?” February 1998.)
The
moral of the story is that with Capital Account Convertibility financial crises
will always be with us; and there is no magic wand to stop them. These
conclusions are important because they should make us appropriately wary about
statements of the form, “we can make free capital flows safe for the world if
we do x at the same time,” where x is the currently fashionable antidote to
crisis. In India today the x is “strengthening the domestic financial system
and improving the prudential standards.” Tomorrow’s x is anybody’s guess.
If we are forced to look for a new series of policy errors each time a crisis
hits, we should be extremely cautious about our ability to prescribe a policy
regime that will sustain a stable system of capital flows. Hence any conclusions
by the special RBI committee would be just another such wishful thinking that
others before us have undertaken, whereas such policies may not be enough from
preventing a crisis in India. The only way to avoid such a crisis is to have
regulated capital inflow into the economy, the purpose of which is defeated by
CAC.