People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVI
No. 31 July 05, 2012 |
Capital
and Public Expenditure Prabhat
Patnaik THERE is a
paradox at the heart of political
economy, which can be seen as follows. Suppose a
capitalist economy is saddled
with substantial unemployment and unutilised productive
capacity, as is the
case now over the entire capitalist world. Suppose in this
situation the State
increases its expenditure by enlarging its fiscal deficit,
i.e. it spends, let
us say, Rs100 more without any increase in its tax
revenue. And let us assume
for simplicity that the capitalist economy is a closed,
isolated one. Then the
Rs100 of expenditure will directly and indirectly, i.e.
via the various rounds
of further expenditure it generates, increase aggregate
demand, and hence
employment, and output in the economy (since no demand
will be leaking out in
the form of larger imports from elsewhere because of the
closed economy
assumption). This increase in output will of course
increase profits as well.
The paradox then consists in this: if a rise in fiscal
deficit increases capitalists’
profits, then why are they so opposed to fiscal deficits?
Why do they keep
harping on “fiscal responsibility”, the financial
capitalists most vocally, but
the others too, though with lesser stridency? It may be thought
at first sight that the problem
arises because we do not have closed capitalist economies,
and that an increase
in the fiscal deficit will leak out in the form of larger
import demand, which
will generate little additional employment at home but
create a balance of
payments problem. But, the capitalists’ opposition to
fiscal deficit arises not
only in countries whose products are uncompetitive and
whose additional demand
therefore leaks out abroad in the form of larger imports;
it arises even in
strongly competitive economies, where recession could be
overcome, and more
profits generated, through a larger fiscal deficit, but
where the capitalists’
opposition prevents this from happening. This opposition
therefore is more
fundamental than merely the fear of a worsening of the
balance of payments,
which brings us back to the question: why do capitalists
oppose fiscal
deficits? WHY
THIS OPPOSITION TO
FISCAL DEFICITS? The typical
answer given to this question is
that fiscal deficits are simply bad policy, and the
opposition of capitalists
to them is because of this fact and has nothing to do with
their self-interest.
Just as a family cannot have a
perpetual excess of expenditure over its income, without
at some point ceasing
to be creditworthy, likewise a government cannot keep
having a perpetual fiscal
deficit. By doing so it gets saddled with mounting debt,
which is bad per se
since it can never hope to pay
back its debt, and which, for that very reason, undermines
its creditworthiness
beyond a certain limit. This, however, is
a completely wrong answer,
since the analogy between the family and the government is
a false analogy. To
start with, if the government uses the fiscal deficit to
make investments in
productive assets, then it is doing something that is in
principle no different
from what corporations do: corporations after all have
always a backlog of debt
but still keep borrowing for making fresh investments. But
even if it is the
case that the fiscal deficit is used to finance
expenditure other than
investment expenditure, or that government investment,
unlike that of
corporations, is not necessarily profit-making (out of
which interest payments
could be made), the government still stands on a very
different footing from
any other entity
in the economy, for two
obvious reasons. One, it has the
power to tax, including even
those from whom it borrows to finance the fiscal deficit.
Indeed the lesser is the
leakage of demand out of the economy, and the more the
fiscal deficit generates
employment and output inside the economy,
the greater is the borrowing from within the economy, and
hence the
government’s capacity to tax the lenders. Two, since the
government can always
take recourse to borrowing from the central bank, which
can print money to meet
its borrowing requirements, the question of the
government’s losing its
creditworthiness simply
does not arise. True, if the
central bank is made “autonomous”
as a result of “financial liberalisation”, and therefore
ceases to be obliged
to lend to the government what it asks for, then the
government loses this
privilege. But since the argument for making it
“autonomous” is precisely to
prevent the government from going on borrowing from it,
such prevention must
have some independent
rationale. For
exploring this independent
rationale
for preventing a perennial fiscal deficit, we must
therefore deliberately
preclude financial liberalisation. It may also be
thought that running a perennial
fiscal deficit of this sort, which is financed by
borrowing from the central
bank, would entail the emergence of inflationary
pressures; but we are talking
about the economy being in the midst of unemployment and
unutilised capacity,
where the need is for increasing, and not curtailing,
aggregate demand. To be
sure, the government should not run a fiscal deficit if
the economy is producing
close to full capacity output, for that may cause
inflation; but why should there
be any objection to its doing so when the economy is mired
in recession? The objection to
a fiscal deficit (at least
beyond a certain minuscule level relative to the gross
domestic product)
implies de facto an
objection to
larger public expenditure that boosts the level of
aggregate demand. Since such
larger public expenditure, if not financed through a
fiscal deficit, would have
to be financed through larger tax revenue, of which the
capitalists would
normally be called upon to provide a part, their
opposition to fiscal deficits
merges with their opposition to larger government
expenditure: the two become
indistinguishable. The question we again come back to is:
why this opposition? Economists,
especially Marxist economists who
have attempted to go deep into the political economy of
the system, have for
long been intrigued by this paradox and have answered it
in a variety of ways.
And all of them have noted that the opposition of
capitalists is never to all forms
of public expenditure, but only to some. Public
expenditure in the form of
“transfer payments” to the poor and working people, even
though the spending
out of such transfers has the effect of increasing output
and capitalists’
profits, is opposed by the latter because it increases the
bargaining power of
the workers. Likewise public expenditure in specific
spheres, even when it
increases aggregate
demand and
profits, tends to compete with private interests in those
spheres in which it
is undertaken. Thus larger government expenditure in
building hospitals has the
effect of making private hospitals less profitable by
exposing them to public
competition; larger government housing construction has
the effect of reducing
the profitability of private house-builders; and so on.
Capitalists’ opposition
to public expenditure however gets muted if such
expenditure is undertaken neither
in the form of transfer payments nor in spheres where
there is such competition.
And one obvious sphere that satisfies both these
requirements is military
expenditure, which explains, according to Baran and
Sweezy, why post-war capitalism
relied upon larger FUNDAMENTAL
OBJECTIONS
But the
opposition of big capital, especially
financial interests, to public expenditure cannot just be
explained by these
factors alone. There are more fundamental objections,
which also explain why,
in the midst of the current recession, the right-wing
demand in the United
States is not so much for a step up in military
expenditure (which could be
made to appear plausible given the fact that the US is at
present engaged in
two wars), but for a cutback in public expenditure
together with tax
concessions to the super-rich. What explains such policy
advocacy in the midst
of the recession? This brings us to
the crux of the problem. The
fundamental property of a capitalist system is that its
level of output and
employment is determined essentially by the so-called
“state of confidence” of
the capitalists. When they feel “confident”, they invest;
and this raises the
level of aggregate demand, and hence output and
employment. When they do not
feel “confident”, the opposite happens. To be sure, this
does not mean that the
functioning of a capitalist economy is purely a matter of
psychology. Undoubtedly, the capitalists’
outlook is governed by
what their actual experience has been, i.e. how certain
objective indicators
have behaved (e.g. - whether sales have been increasing). But how this experience is interpreted
and gets translated into
investment decisions depends also upon the state of
“confidence” of the
capitalists. Indeed this fact
is what gives the capitalists an
upper hand. If employment has to increase, then, within the logic of the system, the State
must take steps to
improve the “confidence” of the capitalists. If on the
other hand the State
directly tries to increase employment through its own
expenditure, then that makes
the “state of confidence” of the capitalists irrelevant, and hence amounts implicitly to undermining the
logic of the system and
the role of capitalists within it. This is why all
public expenditure that
directly serves the interests of the capitalists, for
instance investment
subsidies, guaranteed rates of return, input subsidies,
making land available
at throwaway prices, are welcomed by the capitalists, as
are tax-cuts in their
favour. But all public expenditure that by-passes
capitalists and directly
generates employment is opposed by them (with the
exception of military
expenditure). Consider just two
examples. The Cameron
government in This also
explains the fate of Keynesianism.
Keynes was worried that if unemployment continued at high
levels, then capitalism
would succumb to the socialist challenge. So keen was he
to preserve capitalism
that he advocated public expenditure as a means of
directly combating
unemployment, and not indirectly by boosting the “state of
confidence” of the
capitalists. For this unpardonable sin, however, even
Keynes, notwithstanding
the fact that he was trying to protect capitalism, is
shunned by capitalists
today. A barometer of
the “state of confidence” of the
capitalists is the stock market, which in turn reflects
the “state of
confidence” of the financial speculators. Finance capital
therefore is
particularly concerned that the “revival of the state of
confidence” route,
which is so advantageous to itself, for generating
employment, must not get
by-passed. The fact that finance capital is particularly
insistent upon “sound
finance”, i.e. eschewing fiscal deficits, can be explained
by this.