People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVI
No. 51 December 23, 2012 |
The
Twelfth Five Year Plan and the External Sector
Prabhat
Patnaik
THE Twelfth Five
Year Plan is being finalised at
a time when the capitalist world is sunk in a severe crisis.
Between 2008 and 2011,
the advanced capitalist countries as a whole have had a
growth rate of 0.3 per cent,
which is virtual stagnation. In 2012, while the
QUESTIONABLE
ASSUMPTIONS
Financing such an
enormous current account
deficit poses a serious problem. Taking the year 2011-12 as
a whole, the net inflows
of FDI, FII, bank loans and other financial flows were not
enough to cover this
massive current deficit; as a result some foreign exchange
reserves had to be
used up. This however portends danger in a “liberalised”
economy since it sends
a signal to speculators that defending the currency would
become that much more
difficult in the future. Running down reserves therefore
cannot constitute a
viable way of financing a current deficit of this order in a
“liberalised”
economy. The question that arises in this context is: how
does the Twelfth Plan
cope with this problem? And the simple answer is that it
does so by making two
assumptions, each of which is extremely questionable.
The first
assumption is that the intensity of
the world capitalist crisis will abate soon, because of
which our exports will
pick up, so much so that exports as a percentage of GDP at
current prices,
which were on average at 14.7 per cent for the eleventh plan
period, will
reach, again on average, 18.0 per cent for the Twelfth Plan
period. In 2012-13
itself, exports as a percentage of GDP are visualised in the
Plan document to
reach 17.8 per cent; since an average growth rate of 8.2 per
cent in real terms
is expected over the Plan period, what this means is that
(assuming that the
export price index and the GDP price deflator move at more
or less the same
rate over the Plan period) exports in real terms will also
increase at over 8
per cent during this period. Now, unless significant growth
gets generated in
the advanced capitalist countries this is simply not
possible. And what is
more, the Obama administration is likely to put stronger
restrictions on
outsourcing of work by US companies than it has done so far,
if the crisis
continues, which would make the going even tougher for our
exports.
The Twelfth Plan
document’s assumption therefore
is that the crisis will not continue.
But there is no reason why this should be so. The Eurozone
is still in the
woods, with tight austerity measures in place. The US may
well decide to come
down from the so-called “fiscal cliff” that has been in the
news of late, by
cutting government expenditure and raising taxes, which
would push the economy
back into stagnation or even recession; and even if no
effective tightening
occurs as a result of the “fiscal cliff” negotiations, the
fiscal policy in
general will nonetheless be shaped on the basis of agreement
between Obama and
the Congress, which will almost certainly entail some
austerity. Hence the
crisis of the advanced capitalist countries will continue in
the foreseeable
future, and may even call forth protectionism in the
The second
assumption made in the Plan document
is even more questionable, and this is that raising the
domestic savings rate
relative to the investment rate will bring down the current
account deficit.
This is bizarre since it amounts to saying, for instance,
that no matter what
the world scenario is we can
always, in a “liberalised” economy, manage our current
account deficit with
impunity, ie, without causing a domestic recession, by
reducing our fiscal
deficit (which is one way of raising the domestic
savings rate relative to
the investment rate). This is a novel argument for
“austerity”, that says in
effect that “austerity” in a “liberalised” economy can
resolve the balance of
payments problems in all seasons without any adverse impact
on the GDP.
The analytical
error of this argument can be
seen from a simple numerical example. In any economy, a part
of the total
income is consumed, a part is invested and a part
constitutes current surplus (a
deficit is merely a negative surplus). For example if an
economy has a total
income of 100, its consumption (taking both government and
private sectors
together) may be 70, its investment (again taking both
sectors together) may be
35, in which case its current deficit will be 5. This
current deficit in turn
is nothing else but the excess of imports (both merchandise
and services) over the
aggregate of its exports (both merchandise and services),
its net investment
incomes from abroad and its net remittance inflows. Let us
for simplicity ignore
all these other items, and assume that the deficit arises
from an export of 15
against an import of 20. The excess of income over
consumption (both government
and private) constitutes domestic savings, which in our
example is 30. Hence
the current deficit is nothing else but the excess of
domestic investment over
domestic savings (ie, 35-30 in our example). And this is
ostensibly why the
Plan says that we can close our current deficit by, say,
keeping investment at
35 but raising savings also to 35.
The fallacy of this
argument however is this:
our exports, determined by world conditions, will not
necessarily change if we
tax more at home; they will remain, say, at 15. Now, a rise
in savings by 5, or
a fall in consumption from 70 to 65, will close the current
deficit while
keeping total income at 100, only if the
entire reduction in consumption is of imported consumption
goods. If the
reduction in consumption is of domestically-produced
consumption goods, then
the current deficit will not be affected while there will be
a recession at
home. (This recession may have second-order effects on the
current deficit, reducing
it; but the basic point is that income can no longer remain
at 100, and any
closing of the current deficit occurs because of the fall in
income). Even if
the reduction in consumption falls partly on imported goods
and partly on
domestically-produced goods, even then there will be a
recession, and income
will fall below 100.
The Draft Plan
however does not visualise any
possibility of recession at all. It assumes an 8.2 per cent
growth rate in GDP
over the Twelfth Plan for an average fixed investment rate
of 34 per cent,
which gives a capital-output ratio (incremental) of 4.15. In
the eleventh plan
period, there was according to it a growth rate of 7.9 per
cent for an average
fixed investment rate of 32.9 per cent which again gives a
capital-output ratio
of 4.16. The Draft Plan therefore has assumed that the
increase in output in
the Indian economy will be determined entirely by the
increase in its fixed
capital stock, ie, from the supply side, which means that
there will be no
demand-side constraints on output, ie, no recession. By
assuming that there
will be no shortfall in demand, and that the output will be
at its maximal
level (given the capital stock), even when the domestic
savings are being
raised to curtail the current balance, the Draft Plan is
implicitly supposing
that the entire rise
in savings will be
immediately at the expense of imports, ie, the entire
reduction in consumption
will be directly at the expense of imported goods.
RECESSIONARY
EFFECT
Not only is this
unrealistic in general; but
given the manner of increasing savings that it suggests, it
is wholly absurd.
One way of raising savings it suggests for instance is
through cutting
subsidies which would increase government savings (by
reducing the fiscal
deficit). Now, the poor hardly consume any imported goods
directly; whatever
imported goods they consume are consumed indirectly
(through, for instance,
imported oil going as diesel input into the ferrying of some
goods they
consume). A reduction in subsidies that curtails their
consumption therefore
must reduce the demand for home-produced goods (even if the
second-order
effects of such reduction is to curb imports). In other
words raising the
domestic savings ratio by curtailing the consumption of the
poor will
necessarily have a recessionary effect on the economy, which would then mean that the entire Twelfth Plan
calculations, based
on the assumption of a constant capital-output ratio (ie,
the absence of any
demand constraint) become invalid.
The real reason for
asking for a curtailment of
subsidies and a reduction of the fiscal deficit through these means (rather than by taxing the
rich), is that this
is exactly what finance capital wants. It will countenance
neither a large
fiscal deficit nor an increase in taxes on the rich, as is
evident from fiscal
policies being pursued all over the world, starting from the
US itself, in the
contemporary era of hegemony of international finance. The
government of India,
precisely because it wishes to appease globalised finance in
order to induce it
to flow into the country to bridge the current account
deficit, is keen not
only on reducing the fiscal deficit, but on doing so at the expense of the people rather than at the
expense of the rich.
What the Draft Plan presents is spurious theory to justify
this attack on the
people.
But no matter what
it does, financial inflows
are unlikely to bridge the current account deficit, even as
the basic
calculations of the Plan are invalidated by this deficit.
The alternative is to
put in place suitable controls on imports and on
cross-border capital flows,
which not only constitute an effective means of coping with
current account
deficits, but also promise freedom to the State from the
obligation to pursue
policies in keeping with the caprices of finance capital.
But this alternative
requires a different class orientation on the part of the
State.